← Back to Insights
August 24, 2016
Download PDF 
Authors
David W. Johnson
Topics
Economics Policy
Channels
Commentaries

The Big Lift: Improving Public Health Exchanges

Bring out the Xanax. Anxiety among Obamacare supporters is skyrocketing. The bad news just keeps coming. Aetna has joined UnitedHealthcare and Humana in announcing plans to exit almost all public marketplaces. Remaining health insurers are increasing rates by double-digit margins: most over 20%; some over 40%.

Enrollment is far below projections. Those enrolling are disproportionately sick and high-users of healthcare services. Large percentages of younger, healthier Americans prefer to pay modest penalties (hundreds of dollars) rather than spend thousands on health insurance.

The net results are higher costs and less choice for health exchange consumers. Bloomberg reports as many as a quarter of America’s counties, mostly rural, may only have a single insurer offering ACA-compliant health plans for 2017. With Aetna’s withdrawal, Pinal County in Arizona currently has no insurer licensed to provide 2017 coverage.

Given these realities, President Obama and presidential candidate Hillary Clinton favor creating a government-run health insurer (termed “the public option”) to compete with private insurers in underserved markets. This is a terrible idea.

Top-down, centrally-administered, government-run organizations misread or ignore performance signals, misallocate resources and distort market function. They operate inefficiently and generate inferior outcomes. Consider the TSA’s underwhelming performance.

A better approach is to tinker with Obamacare’s design and boost its performance.

heavy1

Pursing Olympic Glory: “Top-Down” China vs. “Bottom-Up” U.S.

Since the 2008 Beijing Olympics, the U.S. and China have been the two most-prolific medal-winning countries. They compete to win gold, silver and bronze medals, but they employ polar-opposite approaches to athletic development.

China operates a massive state-sponsored athletic program to find, train and pay future Olympians. In stark contrast, the private U.S. Olympic and Paralympic Foundation receives no government funding and supports local efforts to groom Olympic-caliber athletes.

This difference in training models creates “a natural experiment” that can measure the relative effectiveness of “top-down” and “bottom-up” organizational models. Medals won are the clear indicators of success.

Winning Olympic medals is an obsession in China. Beginning in the 1950s, the Communist Party began funding state-run athletic programs to groom world-class athletes. Their investment includes thousands of sports boarding schools that enroll students at very young ages and produce 95% of China’s Olympic athletes.

China’s single-minded, state-sponsored pursuit of international athletic glory is losing steam. The Chinese team won only 26 gold and 70 total medals at the Rio Games, down from 51 and 100 at the 2008 Beijing Games. China’s vaunted gymnastics team won only two bronze medals. Critics contend training regimens have become too soft. Others note Chinese parents are less willing to send their young children away to the isolated and grueling sports boarding schools.

The American approach couldn’t be more different. Young athletes participate voluntarily in their chosen sports at local clubs with strong parental support. The better athletes emerge through intense competitions and receive superior coaching at elite, privately-funded training centers. The American Olympic team is ascendant. It won 121 medals in Rio, a record 51 more than the second-place Chinese team.

The scale of the American athletic training is immense. According to USA Gymnastics, over 5 million young people participate in gymnastics. Three-quarters are girls. Over 900,000 train 100+ days per year. “The Final Five” women gymnasts emerged from this vast talent pool to represent the U.S. at the Rio Olympics. They won 4 gold and 9 total medals.

This “natural experiment” yields an obvious conclusion. Governments aren’t any better at picking Olympic champions than they are at picking winning industries or companies. The best performers do not come through “government selection.” They emerge through a natural, bottom-up, evolutionary, market-based selection process.

 heavy2

Intelligent Market Design

 My summer beach reading included Who Gets What – and Why by Stanford economist Alvin Roth. Roth has spent has career studying and engineering “matching” markets where participants make purchasing decisions based on more than product prices.

College selection is an example of a matching market. Prospective students and colleges send signals (e.g. through early admissions) to one another to facilitate appropriate buy-sell decisions. In most cases, “fit” matters more than price.

Markets exist to solve problems, such as finding the right colleges for high school seniors. Markets work best for both buyers and sellers when they are 1. simple; 2. uncongested; 3. limit unforeseen consequences; and 4. provide ample choice. Markets underperform and even fail when they compromise one or more of these 4 characteristics.

Roth stresses that markets require frequent adjustment to function smoothly. In this sense, economists who “design” markets function like engineers. Here’s how Roth describes the process of market design and evolution,

“…not only do marketplaces have to solve the problems of creating a thick market [with ample choice], managing congestion, and ensuring that participation is safe and simple, but they also have to keep solving and resolving these problems as markets evolve.

…market designers can learn a lot about what makes markets succeed by studying those that fail. …a market design won’t succeed unless it avoids each of the ways that it could fail. Often the same competitive impulses that make well-designed markets succeed cause poorly-designed markets to fail.[1]

The U.S. “market” for “matching” high-potential athletes to its Olympic team clearly works. The selection process is straight-forward, deliberate and fair. Participants respect its outcomes. Its winners excel at international competitions.

The same cannot be said for U.S. health exchanges. Matching buyers and sellers of health insurance plans is too complex, contains excessive financial risk and offers too little choice.

The right policy response to market imperfections is better program design. As Alvin Roth would suggest, it’s time to bring out the tool kit and tinker with public exchange mechanics.

heavy3

If They’re Broke, Let’s Fix ‘Em

The public health exchanges are still young. 2016 is only their third year of operations. All new markets produce insights and contain surprises. The bullets below chronicle several insights and surprises from public health exchanges. They should inform and guide its improvement.

  • The public exchanges exist to solve the problem of matching individuals who want to purchase health insurance with companies that want to sell health insurance.

 

  • The public exchanges have added roughly 11 million new enrollees who previously lacked health insurance. This has led to a meaningful reduction in the percentage of Americans without health insurance.

 

  • Medicaid enrollment increases have exceeded forecasts across all states, even those not participating in Obamacare’s Medicaid expansion program. Some of this increased enrollment emanates from a “welcome mat” effect. Publicity for Obamacare has stimulated Medicaid-eligible Americans to enroll in greater numbers. Advertising works.

 

  • Performance among health exchanges is variable. Several are running well, have ample plan selections and enlightened state regulation. For example, California limits out-of-pocket drug costs and may drop health plans that don’t meet targeted quality standards.

 

  • Disproportionately sick people have purchased higher-cost, higher benefit health plans. This has created “moral hazard” for health insurance companies. Subscribers have a better sense of their healthcare needs and are transferring that risk to health plan sponsors.

 

  • Special enrollment provisions are too liberal. They allow individual subscribers to game the system. Too many enrollees purchase coverage only when they need it.

 

  • Public exchange consumers are price-sensitive. They disproportionately purchase lower-cost plans with limited networks.

 

  • Young people disproportionately buy the lowest-cost plans or elect to remain uninsured (and pay a modest penalty).

 

  • Many subscribers cannot afford the high deductibles and co-pays embedded in their health plans.

 

  • To attract new members, many commercial health insurers priced their plans too aggressively. They also relied on broad, expensive coverage networks. These self-imposed decisions have contributed to significant operating losses.

 

  • Selecting the right plan for many consumers has been a complex and frustrating experience.

 

  • Many, particularly rural, markets have limited health plan choices.

 

  • Health insurance coverage does not improve preventive care and chronic disease management. For example, increased coverage has not reduced emergency room visits.

None of these challenges is fatal, but their collective impact is substantial. There will be significant near-term negative impacts in most public exchange marketplaces. These include higher prices, less plan choice and very high deductibles.

Fortunately, there are many concrete steps that government regulators and private market participants can take to enhance performance of public exchanges. Some are easy. They include better educational materials and more focused marketing to potential young enrollees. Independent assessments of health plan offerings and enhanced selection counseling can improve consumer decision-making.

The government is already tightening special enrollment provisions to limit subscriber “gaming.” In many markets, private insurers are experimenting with new coverage models that they believe can operate profitably. These include narrow network products (Oscar) and plans that offer enhanced primary care services (Harken).

Some desirable fixes will require legislation. Loosening rate formularies would enable health plans to price policies for younger people more aggressively. Individual mandate penalties should be higher to discourage non-enrollment. Targeted subsidies can work more effectively. The government could improve and extend “risk-corridor” protections for health insurers to incentivize tighter pricing for health plan offerings.

There are many more policy initiatives marketplace designers could use to improve the public exchanges. Bring them on. It’s time to roll up our sleeves, get to work and fix what’s broken on the public exchanges.

heavy4

More Adam Smith. Less Mao Zedong.

The good news is that the public exchange marketplaces are evolving and getting better at allocating scarce resources efficiently. Private-company engagement and enlightened government regulation can and will improve their design and performance.

Given time and intelligent design, the health exchange markets will achieve equilibrium by balancing prices, coverage, subsidies and regulation. This is the path to more expansive, appropriate and affordable healthcare insurance for more Americans.

As with the selection of U.S. Olympians, we need to let the marketplace determine the fitness of individual health plan offerings. We need to trust that bottom-up, results-oriented processes will meet consumers’ healthcare needs as it does so effectively in other industries.

Importantly, we must resist the temptation of government-run health insurance plans. The “public option” will underwhelm and underperform. Despite massive investment, it would win even fewer medals than Chinese gymnasts did at the Rio Olympics.

 

 

 

 

 

[1] Alvin Roth, Who Gets What – and Why, pp. 52-53

About the Author

David W. Johnson

David Johnson is the CEO of 4sight Health, an advisory company working at the intersection of healthcare strategy, economics, innovation. Johnson is a healthcare thought leader, keynote speaker, and strategic advisor to organizations busting the status-quo to reform our healthcare system. He is the author of Market vs. Medicine: America’s Epic Fight for Better, Affordable Healthcare, and his second book, The Customer Revolution in Healthcare: Delivering Kinder, Smarter, Affordable Care for All (McGraw-Hill 2019). As a speaker, Dave plays the role of rebel, challenger, industry historian, investor and company evaluator to push audiences forward. (Watch bio video.) Johnson applies his 25+ years of investment banking in healthcare to identify ways the healthcare industry must change to deliver better care. He received a Masters in Public Policy from Harvard Kennedy School, an English degree from Colgate University, and served in the African Peace Corp service. Join over 10k+ healthcare executives who read our weekly insights and commentary on www.4sighthealth.comPreorder his third book, The Coming Healthcare Revolution: 10 Forces that Will Cure America’s Health Crisis, now.

 

 

Recent Posts

Innovation
Podcast: Interpreting the Public’s Reaction to the Public Death of a Healthcare CEO 12/12/24
What does the public’s reaction to the execution of a top health insurance executive say about healthcare’s future?… Read More
By December 12, 2024
Outcomes
From Benefit to Business: Did Medicare Privatization Lead to Murder?
The brazen assassination of healthcare insurance executive Brian Thompson, CEO of UnitedHealthcare, has everyone commenting on the deeper… Read More
By December 11, 2024
System Dynamics
Social Media’s Assassination of Brian Thompson
Before dawn on Wednesday, December 4, United Healthcare’s CEO Brian Thompson approached the Hilton Hotel in Midtown Manhattan… Read More
By December 10, 2024